Cargando…

The Hard Problem of Cooperation

Based on individual variation in cooperative inclinations, we define the “hard problem of cooperation” as that of achieving high levels of cooperation in a group of non-cooperative types. Can the hard problem be solved by institutions with monitoring and sanctions? In a laboratory experiment we find...

Descripción completa

Detalles Bibliográficos
Autores principales: Eriksson, Kimmo, Strimling, Pontus
Formato: Online Artículo Texto
Lenguaje:English
Publicado: Public Library of Science 2012
Materias:
Acceso en línea:https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC3392242/
https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pubmed/22792282
http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0040325
_version_ 1782237607277625344
author Eriksson, Kimmo
Strimling, Pontus
author_facet Eriksson, Kimmo
Strimling, Pontus
author_sort Eriksson, Kimmo
collection PubMed
description Based on individual variation in cooperative inclinations, we define the “hard problem of cooperation” as that of achieving high levels of cooperation in a group of non-cooperative types. Can the hard problem be solved by institutions with monitoring and sanctions? In a laboratory experiment we find that the answer is affirmative if the institution is imposed on the group but negative if development of the institution is left to the group to vote on. In the experiment, participants were divided into groups of either cooperative types or non-cooperative types depending on their behavior in a public goods game. In these homogeneous groups they repeatedly played a public goods game regulated by an institution that incorporated several of the key properties identified by Ostrom: operational rules, monitoring, rewards, punishments, and (in one condition) change of rules. When change of rules was not possible and punishments were set to be high, groups of both types generally abided by operational rules demanding high contributions to the common good, and thereby achieved high levels of payoffs. Under less severe rules, both types of groups did worse but non-cooperative types did worst. Thus, non-cooperative groups profited the most from being governed by an institution demanding high contributions and employing high punishments. Nevertheless, in a condition where change of rules through voting was made possible, development of the institution in this direction was more often voted down in groups of non-cooperative types. We discuss the relevance of the hard problem and fit our results into a bigger picture of institutional and individual determinants of cooperative behavior.
format Online
Article
Text
id pubmed-3392242
institution National Center for Biotechnology Information
language English
publishDate 2012
publisher Public Library of Science
record_format MEDLINE/PubMed
spelling pubmed-33922422012-07-12 The Hard Problem of Cooperation Eriksson, Kimmo Strimling, Pontus PLoS One Research Article Based on individual variation in cooperative inclinations, we define the “hard problem of cooperation” as that of achieving high levels of cooperation in a group of non-cooperative types. Can the hard problem be solved by institutions with monitoring and sanctions? In a laboratory experiment we find that the answer is affirmative if the institution is imposed on the group but negative if development of the institution is left to the group to vote on. In the experiment, participants were divided into groups of either cooperative types or non-cooperative types depending on their behavior in a public goods game. In these homogeneous groups they repeatedly played a public goods game regulated by an institution that incorporated several of the key properties identified by Ostrom: operational rules, monitoring, rewards, punishments, and (in one condition) change of rules. When change of rules was not possible and punishments were set to be high, groups of both types generally abided by operational rules demanding high contributions to the common good, and thereby achieved high levels of payoffs. Under less severe rules, both types of groups did worse but non-cooperative types did worst. Thus, non-cooperative groups profited the most from being governed by an institution demanding high contributions and employing high punishments. Nevertheless, in a condition where change of rules through voting was made possible, development of the institution in this direction was more often voted down in groups of non-cooperative types. We discuss the relevance of the hard problem and fit our results into a bigger picture of institutional and individual determinants of cooperative behavior. Public Library of Science 2012-07-09 /pmc/articles/PMC3392242/ /pubmed/22792282 http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0040325 Text en Eriksson, Strimling. http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are properly credited.
spellingShingle Research Article
Eriksson, Kimmo
Strimling, Pontus
The Hard Problem of Cooperation
title The Hard Problem of Cooperation
title_full The Hard Problem of Cooperation
title_fullStr The Hard Problem of Cooperation
title_full_unstemmed The Hard Problem of Cooperation
title_short The Hard Problem of Cooperation
title_sort hard problem of cooperation
topic Research Article
url https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC3392242/
https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pubmed/22792282
http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0040325
work_keys_str_mv AT erikssonkimmo thehardproblemofcooperation
AT strimlingpontus thehardproblemofcooperation
AT erikssonkimmo hardproblemofcooperation
AT strimlingpontus hardproblemofcooperation