Cargando…
Two for the price of one: If moving beyond traditional single‐best discrete choice experiments, should we use best‐worst, best‐best or ranking for preference elicitation?
This study undertook a head‐to‐head comparison of best‐worst, best‐best and ranking discrete choice experiments (DCEs) to help decide which method to use if moving beyond traditional single‐best DCEs. Respondents were randomized to one of three preference elicitation methods. Rank‐ordered (exploded)...
Autores principales: | , , , |
---|---|
Formato: | Online Artículo Texto |
Lenguaje: | English |
Publicado: |
John Wiley and Sons Inc.
2022
|
Materias: | |
Acceso en línea: | https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC9826006/ https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pubmed/36102864 http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/hec.4599 |
_version_ | 1784866749432201216 |
---|---|
author | Huls, Samare P. I. Lancsar, Emily Donkers, Bas Ride, Jemimah |
author_facet | Huls, Samare P. I. Lancsar, Emily Donkers, Bas Ride, Jemimah |
author_sort | Huls, Samare P. I. |
collection | PubMed |
description | This study undertook a head‐to‐head comparison of best‐worst, best‐best and ranking discrete choice experiments (DCEs) to help decide which method to use if moving beyond traditional single‐best DCEs. Respondents were randomized to one of three preference elicitation methods. Rank‐ordered (exploded) mixed logit models and respondent‐reported data were used to compare methods and first and second choices. First choices differed from second choices and preferences differed between elicitation methods, even beyond scale and scale dynamics. First choices of best‐worst had good choice consistency, scale dynamics and statistical efficiency, but this method's second choices performed worst. Ranking performed best on respondent‐reported difficulty and preference; best‐best's second choices on statistical efficiency. All three preference elicitation methods improve efficiency of data collection relative to using first choices only. However, differences in preferences between first and second choices challenge moving beyond single‐best DCE. If nevertheless doing so, best‐best and ranking are preferred over best‐worst DCE. |
format | Online Article Text |
id | pubmed-9826006 |
institution | National Center for Biotechnology Information |
language | English |
publishDate | 2022 |
publisher | John Wiley and Sons Inc. |
record_format | MEDLINE/PubMed |
spelling | pubmed-98260062023-01-09 Two for the price of one: If moving beyond traditional single‐best discrete choice experiments, should we use best‐worst, best‐best or ranking for preference elicitation? Huls, Samare P. I. Lancsar, Emily Donkers, Bas Ride, Jemimah Health Econ Research Articles This study undertook a head‐to‐head comparison of best‐worst, best‐best and ranking discrete choice experiments (DCEs) to help decide which method to use if moving beyond traditional single‐best DCEs. Respondents were randomized to one of three preference elicitation methods. Rank‐ordered (exploded) mixed logit models and respondent‐reported data were used to compare methods and first and second choices. First choices differed from second choices and preferences differed between elicitation methods, even beyond scale and scale dynamics. First choices of best‐worst had good choice consistency, scale dynamics and statistical efficiency, but this method's second choices performed worst. Ranking performed best on respondent‐reported difficulty and preference; best‐best's second choices on statistical efficiency. All three preference elicitation methods improve efficiency of data collection relative to using first choices only. However, differences in preferences between first and second choices challenge moving beyond single‐best DCE. If nevertheless doing so, best‐best and ranking are preferred over best‐worst DCE. John Wiley and Sons Inc. 2022-09-14 2022-12 /pmc/articles/PMC9826006/ /pubmed/36102864 http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/hec.4599 Text en © 2022 The Authors. Health Economics published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd. https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/This is an open access article under the terms of the http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/) License, which permits use and distribution in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited, the use is non‐commercial and no modifications or adaptations are made. |
spellingShingle | Research Articles Huls, Samare P. I. Lancsar, Emily Donkers, Bas Ride, Jemimah Two for the price of one: If moving beyond traditional single‐best discrete choice experiments, should we use best‐worst, best‐best or ranking for preference elicitation? |
title | Two for the price of one: If moving beyond traditional single‐best discrete choice experiments, should we use best‐worst, best‐best or ranking for preference elicitation? |
title_full | Two for the price of one: If moving beyond traditional single‐best discrete choice experiments, should we use best‐worst, best‐best or ranking for preference elicitation? |
title_fullStr | Two for the price of one: If moving beyond traditional single‐best discrete choice experiments, should we use best‐worst, best‐best or ranking for preference elicitation? |
title_full_unstemmed | Two for the price of one: If moving beyond traditional single‐best discrete choice experiments, should we use best‐worst, best‐best or ranking for preference elicitation? |
title_short | Two for the price of one: If moving beyond traditional single‐best discrete choice experiments, should we use best‐worst, best‐best or ranking for preference elicitation? |
title_sort | two for the price of one: if moving beyond traditional single‐best discrete choice experiments, should we use best‐worst, best‐best or ranking for preference elicitation? |
topic | Research Articles |
url | https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC9826006/ https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pubmed/36102864 http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/hec.4599 |
work_keys_str_mv | AT hulssamarepi twoforthepriceofoneifmovingbeyondtraditionalsinglebestdiscretechoiceexperimentsshouldweusebestworstbestbestorrankingforpreferenceelicitation AT lancsaremily twoforthepriceofoneifmovingbeyondtraditionalsinglebestdiscretechoiceexperimentsshouldweusebestworstbestbestorrankingforpreferenceelicitation AT donkersbas twoforthepriceofoneifmovingbeyondtraditionalsinglebestdiscretechoiceexperimentsshouldweusebestworstbestbestorrankingforpreferenceelicitation AT ridejemimah twoforthepriceofoneifmovingbeyondtraditionalsinglebestdiscretechoiceexperimentsshouldweusebestworstbestbestorrankingforpreferenceelicitation |